Recently in growth Category

An interesting article on robotics today and trends for the future.  My introductory economics class this semester will have writing assignment that are partly graded by machine.

Skilled Work, Without the Worker
- August 18, 2012
An op-ed piece that appeared at www.voxeu.org on May 4th, by Rick Evans, Larry Kotlikoff and Kerk Phillips and based on this paper.

Alex Tabarrok blogs about the piece at Marginal Revolution.

Fiscal sustainability and generational equity are two of the most pressing policy issues of our times. Yet these two highly related concerns are difficult to clearly define, let alone measure.

The standard metric of long-term fiscal imbalance is official government debt (Reinhart and Rogoff 2009). But, as shown in Green and Kotlikoff (2009), official debt, like time and distance in physics, is not a well-defined economic concept.

What Causes Economic Growth?

Today's column from the Deseret News

This semester I have been teaching a class at BYU on economic growth.  One of the anticlimactic moments in the class comes near the end when I try to summarize the various theories and models of growth we have covered.  We try to determine by an appeal to the evidence which of these is the best explanation of observed growth patterns.  The bottom line is that we don't really know.

What Lies Ahead for North Korea?

This article appeared in the Deseret News on December 27th.

Kim Jung-il, the ruler of North Korea, died last week, reportedly of a massive stroke.  Other than a few deluded souls who might have been sincerely crying their eyes out on North Korean television, he will be missed by no one.

His death does, however, open up the possibility of changes in that reclusive country's policies, both domestically and internationally.  In terms of politics and policy, North Korea is probably the hardest country in the world to reliably understand.  We can observe the final results of whatever process determines policy, but very few people outside North Korea have any clue how that process actually proceeds.  So it is entirely possible that nothing will change in practical terms as a result of Kim Jung-il's death.  Still, if you are a bit of a gambler, the odds are higher now than they have been in a long time.

This article appeared in the Deseret News on June 28th, 2011.

In May, former Minnesota governor, Tim Pawlenty, declared his candidacy for the presidency of the United States. He also released a plan that is intended to lead to a revival of the US economy, which is in the middle of an anemic recovery. One of the key assumptions of this plan is that the economy can be coaxed and prodded into growing at an annual rate of five percent for a decade or more. As economist Donald Marron has pointed out, the US economy has grown at an average rate of 5% for ten years exactly once since the end of World War II. That was the period from mid-1958 to mid-1968. As he puts it, "Getting up to 5% over the next decade thus seems not merely ambitious, but almost unthinkable."

However, Stanford macroeconomist, John B. Taylor, argues that 5% is quite doable. One percent growth per year can come from growth of the population. Taylor argues another one percent can come from having a greater percentage of the population employed as workers. The remaining growth needs to come from increases in the productivity of capital and workers - what economists call total factor productivity or TFP for short. Since 1996 TFP has grown at an average rate of 2.7%, so the remaining three percent needed is not that hard to imagine.

When discussing growth it is important to distinguish between two different effects. The first is a levels effect. This occurs when something happens to permanently raise or lower the long-run productive capacity of the economy. For example, a one-time increase in the population due to a baby boom, or a relaxation of immigration constraints would give us a larger workforce and increase the amount of goods and services we could produce. Levels effects will cause the economy to grow in the short run as it adjusts slowly to incorporate these new resources. In the long run, however, the economy reaches a new higher level and then stays there without any further growth.

A second effect is a growth effect. This is a change that does not necessarily change the productive capacity of the economy immediately, but rather causes it to grow more rapidly over time. An increase in the rate at which new knowledge is discovered and turned into useful products would cause the economy to grow more rapidly over time, and these increases would continue for a long time without gradually petering out as level effects must necessarily do.

Pawlenty's plan calls for reductions in tax rates, balancing the federal budget, easing government regulation, and encouraging sound monetary policy. All of these are laudable goals, but they are also examples of levels effects. Eliminating burdensome regulation, for example, would allow firms to produce more efficiently and lead to increased production. It would also cause firms to hire more workers and invest in greater amounts of capital and machinery. However, once the firms have fully adjusted, there will be no additional economic growth.

If economic policies focus solely on these types of levels effects, then it might be possible to generate a decade's worth of growth in the neighborhood of five percent, but growth would not be sustainable at that level for much longer than that. To have long-lasting high growth rates, policy makers will need to focus on growth effects.

MIT economist Robert Solow won the Nobel Prize in 1987 for his pioneering work in economic growth. One his most important contributions was to show that much observable growth comes from increases in hard-to-measure intangibles that economists lump together and term "technology." Technological progress is now regarded as the primary engine of long-run, sustained growth. To raise the long-run growth of the economy, policy will need to focus on encouraging the expansion of technology.

Some countries, particularly developing ones, try to increase technology by government industrial policy. While this may be somewhat effective for economies that are catching up with the world technology leaders, it does not work well with economies that are already technologically advanced.

For countries like the US a much better approach is to put incentives into place that encourage the production of new ideas and technologies. Tax deductions or tax credits for research and development are one way to do this. Better enforcement of patents and other intellectual property would encourage firms and entrepreneurs to engage in more research and development as well.

Five percent growth for a decade is not an impossible goal for the US economy, but if it is to come about it will require careful consideration and implementation of policies that encourage investment in new ideas and technologies. A focus on policies like balancing the budget and reducing government inefficiency will make us better off, but by themselves are unlikely to yield the five percent growth that Mr. Pawlenty has in mind.
Val Lambson pointed me to this great video of comedian Louis CK on the Conan O'Brien show on 10/2/08. The economic content of the video is that technology has progressed so quickly in recent years, but our baseline utility (happiness) adjusts almost immediately. One of my favorite lines is, "how quickly the world owes him something he knew existed only 10 seconds ago."

The May edition of the International Economic Update from the Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas was released on Monday. Two points stand out to me: (1) The global growth forecasts are less optimistic than most U.S. forecasters (e.g., Ben Bernanke), and (2) the ranking of countries by relative size of fiscal stimulus in 2009 puts the U.S. a little further from the top than I expected.

IMFglobalgrowth2009-05.png

Japanese corporate fertility policy

One of my former students sent me this CNN piece about Japanese corporations incentivizing fertility by making their employees go home early from work two days a week. I have a few comments and questions about this article that I'll put in writing below, and a lot more that I will leave to imagination.

Sports and Economic Growth

Two great games on Sunday have resulted in a Cardinals-Steelers Superbowl.  Can this tell us anything about economics?  I'm not sure, but lets compare the cities who boast the two best teams to the city who has claim on the worst team (ever).

Phoenix, the home of the Cardinals, has been one of the fastest growing cities in the US.  Much of this growth is from high-tech industry, like semi-conductor manufacturers.  And its proximity to the regulatory nightmare that is California has certainly helped that growth. 

Pittsburgh, although in the "Rust Belt", has truly blossomed in the last few years.  It has experienced decent population growth and increased the number of jobs in high paying industries like medical services.